Can No Smoking Rules on Property Be Sweeping? 

December, 2009 -

Under the Tobacco acT (r.s.Q., c. t-0.01), employers mUst prohibit their employees from smoKing inside their establishments. howeVer, the act is mute on no smoKing oUtside, on the company’s land. Can an employer be stricter than the Tobacco Act by implementing a no smoking policy intended to entirely ban smoking on its property (establishment and land)?

In March 2009, JeanPierre Lussier, grievance arbitrator, responded positively to this question in the Pratt & Whitney case 1.

In fact, the arbitrator had to determine the validity of the policy pursuant to which smoking was not allowed anywhere on company property (namely, its establishments, entrance ways, parking lots and land).

to illustrate the scope of this policy, the arbitrator noted that the ban targeted, for instance, the employee who, during his break, wanted to smoke in his car parked on company land. It is clear from the arbitration award that by adopting its no smoking policy, Pratt & Whitney wanted to promote its employees’ health thereby increasing their productivity, reducing absenteeism and, as a result, lowering its business costs. Although, on the one hand, this policy is restrictive and seeks to strongly encourage employees to quit smoking, the arbitrator pointed out, on the other hand, that it is in keeping with trends that are increasingly present in our society, that is, to promote no smoking.              

1. was the policy contrary to the collective agreement?

As the collective agreement was mute on the issue of tobacco use and as management’s rights were stipulated in general terms, the arbitrator was of the view that the employer maintained the exclusive right to adopt a no smoking policy.

2. was the policy Unreasonable giVen the broad scope of the ban? to ascertain the scope of such a policy, some sensitive issues had to be analyzed. Did the sweeping smoking ban on company property run counter to the employees’ free will to smoke? Did the

employer thus impose a lifestyle on smoking employees? Where do we draw the line between a company’s legitimate economic interests and the employees’ rights (for instance, the employee’s free choice, on his break, to smoke in his car parked in the company’s parking lot)? the arbitrator listed some examples which

reflected the difficulty of setting the boundaries between the employer’s legitimate interests and the employees’ free will:

“[87] in my opinion, it is not evident

that a policy promoting the health of

employees and the economic interests

of a company is reasonable. in fact, for

that matter, a company could prohibit

its employees from travelling to work

by motorcycle on the grounds that

motorcyclists run a greater risk of having

accidents than car drivers and, in

the event of accident, their injuries are

generally worse. such a prohibition in

effect could be motivated by the desire

to ensure better health and safety for

employees and lower the costs associated

with the potential absenteeism

of injured motorcyclists. the same

could be said for a policy requiring

employees to travel to work using

public transportation since the risks

of having an accident are significantly

lower than if they use their own car.

[88] examples are always somewhat

lame, but what if pratt were to prohibit

its employees from consuming food

containing trans fats while at work.

or, what about a policy requiring

employees to eat a balanced meal

during their lunch break. or a policy

requiring employees to do physical

exercise prior to starting their jobs.

[89] all these policies could be

justified on the basis of a company’s

economic interest in having employees

in better health. scientifically, it could

probably be quite easy to show that

trans fats cause obesity as well as

respiratory and coronary diseases. it

could be shown that employees who

exercise on a regular basis are more

fit, more productive and less prone to

illness than those who do no physical

exercise.

[90] i am giving these examples to

illustrate the fact that a policy can be

justified by the legitimate economic

interests of an employer and still be

perceived as unreasonable because it

directly clashes with the free will of

employees. an employee does not lose

his freedom to choose his lifestyle.

he may decide to come to work by

motorcycle even if he knows that he

runs a greater risk than if he opted

to drive a car. he may travel to work

by car rather than by public transportation.

he may choose to eat “fast

food” every day, even at work, despite

the risks associated with this type of

food. he may choose not to do physical

exercise, etc. [...]”

In the arbitrator’s opinion, where the company’s legitimate interests are at variance with the employee’s personal freedom to choose to smoke, the variance must be resolved by reviewing social values.

thus, the arbitrator considered the various smokingrelated statutes adopted over the years, the purpose of which is to protect nonsmokers from harmful secondary smoke. He concluded that canadian and Quebec legislators have [translation] “introduced restrictive tobacco standards because society is increasingly aware

of the harmful effects of tobacco and wants to be protected from it as much as possible” 2. the arbitrator thus ruled that the policy was reasonable in the following terms.

 

[translation] “[110] in the case under

review, even though the policy

constitutes a strong inducement for

all the employees to stop smoking

and therefore constitutes pressure to

impact on their freedom to choose, it

does not seem unreasonable to me.

it could be unreasonable if it had an

extra-territorial application, that is,

if it obliged employees to become

non-smokers regardless of whether

they are at work or not. in the case at

hand, admittedly, employees are being

pressured to stop smoking, but they

retain the freedom to continue to do

so, even during work periods. in fact,

nothing prevents them from going off

company property during their lunch

break, for example, to smoke one or

more cigarettes. this is, moreover,

what ms. tardif and mr. bourget do.”

 

As the goals of such a policy are legitimate in the case at hand and are consistent with our social values, the arbitrator concluded that it was reasonable.

3. did the policy haVe a discriminatory effect given some employees’ tobacco dependence?

the arbitrator only considered discrimination on the basis of a handicap (nicotine dependence) since the union, in this case, did not raise other rights protected under the Charter of Human Rights and Freedoms, such as the right to privacy. In the case at hand, since the policy included several accommodation measures

3 which the arbitrator deemed reasonable, he considered that the policy was valid despite the discriminatory effect it might have on nicotinedependent employees. In fact, according to the arbitrator,

[translation] “the accommodation measures contained in the policy should be sufficient for a majority of nicotinedependent employees to meet the standard” 4. Nonetheless, the arbitrator added that

[translation] “in the event of medical evidence of serious difficulties despite the accommodation measures contained in the policy, other means of accommodation could be considered” 5 for employees who

are heavily handicapped by their nicotine dependence and for whom most of the accommodation measures contained in the policy would not be enough. thus, although the arbitrator recognized the employer’s right to totally ban its employees from smoking on its property, it is important to note that the arbitrator also concluded that nicotine dependence constitutes a handicap giving rise to accommodation measures. 

In conclusion, the arbitrator recognized the validity of a no smoking policy that is not limited to the prohibitions under the Tobacco Act and that [translation] “encourages no smoking and serves to promote the health of employees, increase their productivity and reduce absenteeism (since many diseases are directly or indirectly tied to smoking) and, as a result, lower the company’s production costs” 6. this arbitration award is interesting since, to date, few decision makers in Quebec have had to consider this issue.

We noted that, to date, few decisions dealing with this issue have been rendered in the other canadian provinces. Despite the fact that case law is not unanimous 7, it stems from some reported decisions that a larger number of decision makers have concluded, as Arbitrator Lussier did, that such policies are reasonable. In short, Arbitrator Lussier’s comments show that business mirrors society and where society evolves, the business adapts and may also evolve in the same direction.

 

MEMBER COMMENTS

WSG Member: Please login to add your comment.

dots